Ad Code

Responsive Advertisement

Ticker

6/recent/ticker-posts

Trade Policies in Developing Countries

Import-Substituting Industrialization: 

From World War II until the 1970s many developing countries attempted to accelerate their development by limiting imports of manufactured goods to substitute a manufacturing sector serving the domestic market. This strategy became popular for a number of reasons, but theoretical economic arguments for import substitution played an important role in its rise. Probably the most important of these arguments was the infant industry argument. 



The Infant Industry Argument:

According to the infant industry argument, developing countries have a potential comparative advantage in manufacturing, but new manufacturing industries in developing countries cannot initially compete with well-established manufacturing in developed countries. To allow manufacturing to get a grip, governments should temporarily support new industries, until they have grown strong enough to meet international competition. Thus, it makes sense, according to this argument, to use tariffs or import quotas as temporary measures to get industrialization started. It is a historical fact that the world's three largest market economies United States, Germany and Japan began their industrialization behind trade barriers. 


Problems with the Infant Industry Argument:

The infant industry argument seems highly reasonable, and in fact it has been convincing to many governments. Yet economists have pointed out many drawbacks in the argument, suggesting that it must be used cautiously 
First, it is not always good to try to move today into the industries that will have a comparative advantage in the future. Suppose that a country that is currently labor abundant is in the process of accumulating capital: When it accumulates enough capital, it will have a comparative advantage in capital-intensive industries. That does not mean it should try to develop these industries immediately. 
Second, protecting manufacturing does no good unless the protection itself helps make industry competitive. Pakistan and India have protected their manufacturing sectors for decades and have recently begun to develop significant exports of manufactured goods. The goods they export, however, are light manufactures like textiles, not the heavy manufactures that they protected. Some economists have warned of the case of the "pseudo infant industry," where industry is initially protected, then becomes competitive for reasons that have nothing to do with the protection. In this case infant industry protection ends up looking like a success but may actually have been a net cost to the economy. 


Market Failure Justifications for Infant Industry Protection: 

To justify the infant industry argument, it is necessary to go beyond the plausible but questionable view that industries always need to be sheltered when they are new. The argument for protecting an industry in its early growth must be related to some particular set of market failures that prevent private markets from developing the industry as rapidly as they should. Supporters of the infant industry argument have identified two market failures as reasons why infant industry protection may be a good idea: 
i. imperfect capital markets 
ii. problem of appropriability 


The imperfect capital markets: 

The imperfect capital markets justification for infant industry protection is as follows. If a developing country does not have a set of financial institutions that would allow savings from traditional sectors (agriculture) to be used to finance investment in new sectors (manufacturing), then growth of new industries will be restricted by the ability of firms in these industries to earn profits. Thus, low initial profits will be an obstacle to investment even if the long-term returns on this investment are high. The first-best policy is to create a better capital market, but protection of new industries, which would raise profits and thus allow more rapid growth, can be justified as a second-best policy option. 


The appropriability argument: 

The appropriability argument for infant industry protection can take many forms, but all have in common the idea that firms in a new industry generate social benefits for which they are not compensated. For example, the firms that first enter an industry may have to incur "start-up" costs of adapting technology to local circumstances or of opening new markets. If other firms are able to follow their lead without incurring these start-up costs, the pioneers will be prevented from reaping any returns from these outlays. Thus, pioneering firms may, in addition to producing physical output, create immaterial benefits (knowledge) in which they are unable to establish property rights. Both the imperfect capital markets argument and the appropriability case for infant industry protection are clearly special cases of the market failures justification for interfering with free trade. 


Promoting Manufacturing Through Protection: 

Although there are doubts about the infant industry argument, many developing countries have seen this argument as a compelling reason to provide special support for the development of manufacturing industries. In most developing countries, however, the basic strategy for industrialization has been to develop industries oriented toward the domestic market by using trade restrictions such as tariffs and quotas to encourage the replacement of imported manufactures by domestic products. The strategy of encouraging domestic industry by limiting imports of manufactured goods is known as the strategy of import-substituting industrialization. By protecting import-substituting industries, countries draw resources away from actual or potential export sectors. So, a country's choice to seek to substitute for imports is also a choice to discourage export growth. The reasons why import substitution rather than export growth has usually been chosen as an industrialization strategy are a mixture of economics and politics. 
First, until the 1970s many developing countries were skeptical about the possibility of exporting manufactured goods (although this skepticism also calls into question the infant industry argument for manufacturing protection). They believed that industrialization was necessarily based on a substitution of domestic industry for imports rather than on a growth of manufactured exports. 
Second, in many cases import-substituting industrialization policies merged naturally with existing political biases. It is also worth pointing out that some advocates of a policy of import substitution believed that the world economy was rigged against new entrants, that the advantages of established industrial nations were simply too great to be overcome by newly industrializing economies. Extreme proponents of this view called for a general policy of delinking developing countries from advanced nations; but even among milder advocates of protectionist development strategies the view that the international economic system systematically works against the interests of developing countries remained common until the 1980s. In most developing economies, the import-substitution drive stopped short of its logical limit: Sophisticated manufactured goods such as computers, precision machine tools, and so on continued to be imported. Nonetheless, the larger countries pursuing importsubstituting industrialization reduced their imports to remarkably low levels. Usually, the smaller a country's economic size the larger will be the share of imports and exports in national income. 

Problems of Import-Substituting Industrialization: 

The attack on import-substituting industrialization starts from the fact that many countries that have pursued import substitution have not shown any signs of catching up with the advanced countries. In some cases, the development of a domestic manufacturing base seems to have led to a stagnation of per capita income instead of an economic takeoff.. Only a few developing countries really seem to have moved dramatically upward on the income scale—and these countries either have never pursued import substitution or have moved sharply away from it. Why didn't import-substituting industrialization work the way it was supposed to? The most important reason seems to be that the infant industry argument was not as universally valid as many people assumed. A period of protection will not create a competitive manufacturing sector if there are fundamental reasons why a country lacks a comparative advantage in manufacturing. Experience has shown that the reasons for failure to develop often run deeper than a simple lack of experience with manufacturing. Poor countries lack skilled labor, entrepreneurs, and managerial competence and have problems of social organization that make it difficult to maintain reliable supplies of everything from spare parts to electricity. These problems may not be beyond the reach of economic policy, but they cannot be solved by trade policy: An import quota can allow an inefficient manufacturing sector to survive, but it cannot directly make that sector more efficient. The infant industry argument is that, given the temporary shelter of tariffs or quotas, the manufacturing industries of less-developed nations will learn to be efficient. In practice, this is not always, or even usually, true. With import substitution failing to deliver the promised benefits, attention has turned to the costs of the policies used to promote industry. On this issue, a growing body of evidence shows that the protectionist policies of many lessdeveloped countries have badly distorted incentives. Part of the problem has been that many countries have used excessively complex methods to promote their infant industries. That is, they have used elaborate and often overlapping import quotas, exchange controls, and domestic content rules instead of simple tariffs. It is often difficult to determine how much protection an administrative regulation is actually providing, and studies show that the degree of protection is often both higher and more variable across industries than the government planned. A further cost that has received considerable attention is the tendency of import restrictions to promote production at an inefficiently small scale. The domestic markets of even the largest developing countries are only a small fraction of the size of that of the United States or the European Union. Often, the whole domestic market is not large enough to allow an efficient-scale production facility. By the late 1980s, the critique of import-substituting industrialization had been widely accepted, not only by economists but by international organizations like the World Bank and even by policymakers in the developing countries themselves. Statistical evidence appeared to suggest that developing countries that followed relatively free trade policies had on average grown more rapidly than those that followed protectionist policies. 

---------------------------------------- 

Problems of the Dual Economy: 

While the trade policy of less-developed countries is partly a response to their relative backwardness as compared with advanced nations, it is also a response to uneven development within the country. Often a relatively modern, capital-intensive, high-wage industrial sector exists in the same country as a very poor traditional agricultural sector. The division of a single economy into two sectors that appear to be at very different levels of development is referred to as economic dualism, and an economy that looks like this is referred to as a dual economy. Why does dualism have anything to do with trade policy? One answer is that dualism is probably a sign of markets working poorly: In an efficient
 economy, for example, workers would not earn hugely different wages in different sectors. Whenever markets are working badly, there may be a market failure case for deviating from free trade. The presence of economic dualism is often used to justify tariffs that protect the apparently more efficient manufacturing sector. A second reason for linking dualism to trade policy is that trade policy may itself have a great deal to do with dualism. As import-substituting industrialization has come under attack, some economists have argued that import-substitution policies have actually helped to create the dual economy or at least aggravate some of its symptoms. 

The Symptoms of Dualism: 

There is no precise definition of a dual economy, but in general a dual economy is one in which there is a "modern" sector that contrasts sharply with the rest of the economy in a number of ways: 
1. The value of output per worker is much higher in the modern sector than in the rest of the economy. In most developing countries, the goods produced by a worker in the manufacturing sector carry a price several times that of the goods produced by an agricultural worker. Sometimes this difference runs as high as 15 to 1. 
2. Accompanying the high value of output per worker is a higher wage rate. Industrial workers may earn ten times what agricultural laborers make. 
3. Although wages are high in the manufacturing sector, however, returns on capital are not necessarily higher. In fact, it often seems to be the case that capital earns lower returns in the industrial sector. 
4. The high value of output per worker in the modern sector is at least partly due to a higher capital intensity of production. Manufacturing in less-developed countries typically has much higher capital intensity than agriculture. In the developing world, agricultural workers often work with primitive tools, while industrial facilities are not much different from those in advanced nations. 
5. Many less-developed countries have a persistent unemployment problem. Especially in urban areas, there are large numbers of people either without jobs or with only occasional, extremely low-wage employment. These urban unemployed coexist with the relatively well-paid urban industrial workers. 


Trade Policy as a Cause of Economic Dualism: 

Trade policy has been accused both of widening the wage differential between manufacturing and agriculture and of fostering excessive capital intensity. The reasons for huge wage differentials between agriculture and industry are not well understood. Some economists believe these differentials are a natural market response. Firms, so the argument goes, offer high wages to ensure low turnover and high work effort in countries not used to the discipline of industrial work. Other economists argue, however, that the wage differentials also reflect the monopoly power of unions whose industries are sheltered by import quotas from foreign competition. With freer trade, they argue, industrial wages would be lower and agricultural wages higher. If so, dualism and unemployment may be worsened by import restrictions, especially those undertaken in the name of import substitution. The excessive capital intensity of manufacturing is partly due to relatively high wages, which give firms an incentive to substitute capital for labor. To the extent that trade restrictions are responsible for these high wages, they are to blame. Also, in some countries a controlled banking system in effect provides subsidized credit to industrial firms, making capital-labor substitution cheap. The most direct channel, however, has been through selective import control. In many cases, imports of capital goods enter without tariff or other restriction, and sometimes with actual import subsidies. This policy further encourages the use of capital-intensive techniques. 

------------------------------------ 

Export-Oriented Industrialization: 


The East Asian Miracle In the 1950s and 1960s it was widely believed that developing countries could create industrial bases only by substituting domestic manufactured goods for imports. From the mid-1960s onward, however, it became increasingly apparent that there was another possible path to industrialization: via exports of manufactured goods, primarily to advanced nations. Moreover, the countries that developed in this manner, a group that the World Bank now refers to as the high-performance Asian economies (HPAEs)—achieved spectacular economic growth, in some cases at more than 10 percent per year. The economies of the HPAEs were severely affected by the financial crisis that began in 1997; nonetheless, their achievements up to that point were remarkable. While the achievement of the HPAEs is not in doubt, and while there is also no question that their success refutes the previous conventional wisdom that industrial development must take place via import substitution, there remain major controversies about the implications of the "East Asian miracle." In particular, different observers place very different interpretations on the role of government policies, including trade policy, in fostering economic growth. 


The Facts of Asian Growth: 

The World Bank's definition of HPAEs contains three groups of countries, whose "miracles" began at different times. First is Japan, which began rapid economic growth soon after World War II and now has per capita income comparable to the United States and Western Europe, which presents trade and industrial policy in advanced countries. In the 1960s rapid economic growth began in four smaller Asian economies, often known as the four "tigers": Hong Kong, Taiwan, South Korea, and Singapore.6 Finally, in the late 1970s and the 1980s rapid growth began in Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia, and, most spectacularly, in China. Each group achieved very high growth rates. Real gross domestic product in the "tiger" economies grew at an average of 8-9 percent from the mid-1960s until the 1997 Asian crisis, compared with 2-3 percent in the United States and Western Europe. Recent growth rates in the other Asian economies have been comparable, and China has reported growth rates of more than 10. In addition to their very high growth rates, the HPAEs have another distinguishing feature: They are very open to international trade and have become more so over time. In fact, the rapidly growing Asian economies are much more export oriented than other developing countries, particularly in Latin America and South Asia. Gross domestic product represents the value added by an economy, not the total sales. Because modern manufacturing often consists of adding a relatively small amount of value to imported inputs, exports can easily exceed total national output. Some economists have tried to tell a simple story that attributes the success of East Asian economies to an "outward-oriented" trade policy. In this view, the high ratios of exports and imports to GDP in Asian nations are the consequences of trade policies that, while they might not correspond precisely to free trade, nonetheless leave trade much freer than in developing countries that have tried to develop through import substitution. And high growth rates are the payoff to this relatively open trade regime. Unfortunately, the evidence for this story is not as strong as its advocates would like. In the first place, it is unclear to what extent the high trade ratios in the HPAEs can really be attributed to free trade policies. With the exception of Hong Kong, the HPAEs have in fact not had anything very close to free trade: All of them continue to have fairly substantial tariffs, import quotas, export subsidies, and other policies that manage their trade. Are the HPAEs following policies that are closer to free trade than those of other developing countries? Probably, although the complexity of the trade policies followed by developing countries in general makes comparisons difficult. 

Industrial Policy in the HPAEs: 

Some commentators believe that the success of the HPAEs, far from demonstrating the effectiveness of free trade policies, actually represents a payoff to sophisticated interventionism. It is in fact the case that several of the highly successful economies have pursued policies that favor particular industries over others; such industrial policies included not only tariffs, import restrictions, and export subsidies, but also more complex policies such as low-interest loans and government support for research and development. Here, we just need to note that most economists studying this issue have been skeptical about the importance of such policies, for at least three reasons. First, HPAEs have followed a wide variety of policies, ranging from detailed government direction of the economy in Singapore to virtual laissez-faire in Hong Kong. South Korea deliberately promoted the formation of very large industrial firms; Taiwan's economy remains dominated by small, family-run companies. Yet all of these economies have achieved similarly high growth rates. Second, despite considerable publicity given to industrial policies, the actual impact on industrial structure may not have been large. The World Bank, in its study of the Asian miracle, found surprisingly little evidence that countries with explicit industrial policies have moved into the targeted industries any faster than those which have not. Finally, there have been some notable failures of industrial policy even in otherwise highly successful economies. For example, from 1973 to 1979 South Korea followed a policy of promoting "heavy and chemical" industries, chemicals, steel, automobiles, and so on. This policy proved extremely costly and was eventually judged to be premature and was abandoned. 


Other Factors in Growth:

In the last few years several researchers have suggested that the whole focus on trade and industrial policy in Asian growth may have been misplaced. After all, international trade and trade policy are only part of the story for any economy, even one with a high ratio of exports to national income. Other aspects of the economy may well have been more important determinants of success. And in fact, the fast-growing Asian economies are distinctive in ways other than their high trade shares. Almost all of these economies, it turns out, have very high savings rates, which means that they are able to finance very high rates of investment. Almost all of them have also made great strides in public education. Several recent estimates suggest that the combination of high investment rates and rapidly improving educational levels explains a large fraction, perhaps almost all, of the rapid growth in East Asia. If this is true, the whole focus on trade and industrial policy is largely misplaced. Perhaps one can argue that the Asian economies have had trade policy that is good in the sense that it has permitted rapid growth, but it is greatly overstating the importance of that policy to say that it caused growth. One thing is, however, certain about the East Asian experience. Whatever else one may say about it, it definitely refutes some assumptions about economic development that used to be widely accepted. First, the presumption that industrialization and development must be based on an inward-looking strategy of import substitution is clearly false. On the contrary, the success stories of development have all involved an outward-looking industrialization based on exports of manufactured goods. Second, the pessimistic view that the world market is rigged against new entrants, preventing poor countries from becoming rich, has turned out to be spectacularly wrong: Never in human history have so many people seen their standard of living rise so rapidly.
 
------------------------------
Reactions

Post a Comment

0 Comments

Ad Code

Responsive Advertisement